Thursday, October 29, 2009

DOS gets an upgrade

Read here. Data collection for Census 2010 will apparently be internet-based.

Monday, October 26, 2009

September CPI: Raya Blues Again

Almost loss in the shuffle of Friday's budget was the CPI report for September. Not that there were any surprises (index numbers, log annual and monthly changes, 2005=100):





As the impact of the fuel price hikes in July fade, you'll see inflation ticking up again. The faster pace of price increases in September can be squarely blamed on Ramadhan, for obvious reasons. To underscore this, here's the chart for my pseudo-core inflation measure(index numbers, log annual changes, 2005=100):





Note that even as growth in the main index started climbing, growth in the core index has dropped. Reading the numbers from DOS' report shows food, transport and miscellaneous items contributed to the bulk of the increase.

Otherwise, I'd consider September's developments encouraging. Price pressures indicate higher economic activity, which augurs well for a higher consumption reading for 3Q 2009. But again, that's really just the Raya effect, and not necessarily a symptom of a more solid rebound in the economy.

Friday, October 23, 2009

Budget 2010: I'm (Mostly) Happy

…because lots of things on my wish list got ticked. Improve education? Check. More money for vocational schools? Check. Remove fuel subsidies? Mostly check. Do something for the lower-income groups and not just the poor? Check. But I’m getting ahead of myself. The numbers look half-decent to me:



But this is planned expenditure and expected revenue, either of which may change as we go through the year. The forecast is for a budget deficit of 5.6%, which isn’t bad either. As you can see from the charts above, most of the drop from this year’s expected deficit of 7.4% is coming from a rather savage cut in operating expenditure. The savings were garnered from a planned drop in procurement, subsidies and especially from “others”. I can’t imagine that would make many government contractors very happy.

Based on these numbers and a projected outstanding debt of about RM420 billion by the end of 2010, we’re looking at the debt to GDP ratio reaching 58.0%, which ain’t good. It’s not quite the all-time high (69.7% in 1987) but it’s getting a little close for comfort. On the other hand the banking system is still awash in liquidity, which means there’s still plenty of capacity to absorb government borrowing without impacting private sector lending. With any luck, we should have a firmer recovery in place by 2011, and we can start on fiscal consolidation by then – or at least, get the pace of borrowing below the economy’s growth rate.

My notes on some of the things that stood out for me in the budget speech:

1. As expected, the government revised upwards the growth forecast for this year to -3.0% from -4.0%-5.0%. Next year’s forecast is between 2.0% to 3.0% - encouraging but not great, as it implies that there will be little closing of the output gap and because with population growth at the upper end of that figure, real per capita income growth will essentially be flat to slightly negative (the +2.5% increase quoted by the PM is in nominal terms).

2. 48k projects under the stimulus packages completed and another 40k projects going on right now – impressive numbers until you look at the government’s account at BNM. September figures aren’t out yet, but as of August the government was sitting on RM25.6 billion in cash, which means projects aren’t being implemented as fast as the government is ready to finance them.

3. Note the introduction of Public-Private Partnerships, which at least have the benefit of having projects in the pipeline. You may remember that RM20b Private Finance Initiatives (PFIs) were mentioned in 9MP as another method of reducing the need for public development spending. Try as I might, I can find no evidence in the last five years that any PFI initiatives were even begun, much less completed.

4. New privatization program? Does this mean Khazanah will be letting go its holdings? How is Ekuinas affected?

5. Rationalising R&D efforts, establishing National Innovation Centre and integrating R&D with patent, copyright and trademark registration. Don’t think this is enough – how about triple deduction on R&D spending?

6. RM0.9b for the tourism industry and a whole slew of initiatives – thumbs up. Also kudos for PR status equivalence between males and females marrying Malaysians.

7. 10MBit broadband? Where? How much? And will it stay up? And RM500 tax allowance barely covers the cost even if you’re taking the cheapest packages. Does wireless qualify? 3G?

8. Halal industry – too little too late I think. But the effort’s appreciated.

9. RM0.5b for agriculture. I’m still waiting for the shoe to drop and someone discovers that we’re neglecting doing anything about domestic distribution.

10. RM1.0b for incentives and subsidies to farmers and fishermen. Why not just give handouts? It’ll probably be more effective. Some of the “incentives” that used to be offered had some perverse effects.

11. GreenTechnology investment – not unexpected

12. Bringing pre-school education into the national system – about time. I’m wondering what this might mean in terms of employment of pre-school teachers.

13. Prestige schools and recognition of head masters – elitism? Or introducing competition into the school system? Time will tell. This isn't a new idea, but at least the government is listening.

14. For students, 4 measures that are bound to be popular – 30 non-race based national scholarships, converting loans to scholarships for 1st class honours, 50% discount for KTM rides, and best of all, subsidized broadband and netbook purchases. Lucky b****rs.

15. RM1.3b to improve polytechnics and community colleges, RM1.1b for training and vocational institutes. I really like this. Trying to put everyone through university education never struck me as a good strategy – you just get poor quality graduates. At least this way, some of our youth have a fighting chance at getting good jobs that don’t necessarily need an academic education, an education they might not be suited for. And I really like having SKM on the same level as diploma holders. I’m reminded of Germany’s apprenticeship system here, and it’s a potential solution towards upgrading our manufacturing capabilities and breaking reliance on low-wage type jobs.

16. Ar-Rahnu microcredit program – I don’t like this on principle. The whole idea of microcredit as pioneered by Grameen was to provide financing based on need and desire for work, not on the ability to put up collateral. The way this is structured, it just confines the hardcore poor in a poverty trap, surviving on handouts.

17. Still no GST!

18. RPGT is coming back!

19. RM10k for each AP! Woot!

20. Fuel subsidies abolished! Kind of. What the new system will be like and how it will be managed are still unknown. I’d actually go further and slap a tax on petrol for those who don’t qualify for the subsidy. The proceeds could help fund investment in green technologies.

21. Government child care centres! Now if only the private sector would follow suit.

22. Individual income tax cut to 26% and personal allowance raised to RM9k. I didn’t expect this and I’m not sure it’s warranted. It’s definitely a significant boost to consumer spending power, at least for those who pay taxes and especially those who are in the top tax bracket. But with the tax base already so narrow, I’m not sure this is a good move at all. Add the RM1k increase in the allowance for annuities and KWSP contributions, and you’re talking about narrowing the tax base even further.

23. Urban poor to include those earning less than RM3k – but with only RM48 million allocated for urban poverty eradication, that’s like spitting into the wind.

24. More trains for Komuter and LRT – I don’t think these will be enough, based on recent experience. Congestion has been increasing so rapidly, that these will only be stop-gap measures.

Overall, I'm not down on this budget - there were some gaps, but there were also some truly good ideas here. I can just imagine civil servants trying to get to grips with outcome based budgeting! Compared to DAP's alternative budget, this one's way weaker on transport, but much stronger (in my opinion) on education.

Thursday, October 22, 2009

Trade Elasticities and the Ringgit

This post ought to make happy those who think that the Ringgit should appreciate to force Malaysian firms to be more competitive, as well as those who think the currency is being manipulated for export competitiveness.

Some background is called for here. What’s an elasticity? In simple terms, it’s the response of one variable to a change in another. In the present post, I’m calculating the response of exports and imports to a change in demand and supply variables, specifically the exchange rate (both nominal and real trade-weighted indexes), Malaysian GDP, as well as external GDP.

In the literature, for a change in the exchange rate to affect the trade balance, then the sum of the absolute values of the exchange elasticity of exports and imports have to be greater than unity (1). This is known as the Marshall-Lerner condition.

Since my formulation of exchange rates is different (for simplification purposes I use the reciprocal of the normal definition), then for the Marshall-Lerner condition to hold my calculated sum of exchange elasticities should be less than -1.

Some disclaimers before proceeding: I’m not using any lag structure (past values of variables), even though I really ought to – economic variables do not respond instantaneously to changes in other economic variables.

Also by rights, the variables should be used within a vector autoregression model rather than the single equation estimates I’m using here, to capture feedback effects and dynamics – but the models I’ve tried so far were unstable and generated some perverse results (Malaysian GDP granger causing World GDP for instance). I’m going to continue working on that, as using a VAR is the more technically correct approach (you run up straight against the Lucas critique otherwise), but the current estimates will have to do for now.

The demand model specifications are:

Log(exports) = log(exchange rate) + log(World GDP) + monthly seasonal dummies

Log(imports) = log(exchange rate) + log(Malaysian GDP) + log(exports) + monthly seasonal dummies


Data is at monthly frequencies (with interpolated GDP data), and the sample period is 2000:1 to 2007:12. World GDP was proxied by using a trade-weighted geometric average of US, Japan, EU, China and Singapore GDP (Malaysia’s five biggest trading partners). For the import demand functions, I had to use an ARCH model rather than standard OLS.

So what did I get?

For nominal exchange rates:

Exports
A 1% appreciation in the exchange rate results in a 1.55% fall in exports

A 1% rise in world GDP results in a 1.50% rise in exports


Imports
A 1% appreciation in the exchange rate results in a 0.28% rise in imports

A 1% rise in exports results in a 0.97% rise in imports

Changes in Malaysian GDP had no significant effects on imports


For real exchange rates:

Exports
A 1% appreciation in the exchange rate results in a 1.57% fall in exports

A 1% rise in world GDP results in a 1.49% rise in exports


Imports
A 1% appreciation in the exchange rate results in a 0.34% rise in imports

A 1% rise in exports results in a 0.99% rise in imports

Changes in Malaysian GDP had no significant effects on imports


So a depreciation in the exchange rate (“weaker” if you will) does result in an increase in the trade balance, as the Marshall-Lerner condition holds for both nominal and real exchange rates. Adding the export elasticity with the import elasticity yields:

Nominal
-1.55 - 0.28 = -1.83

Real
-1.57 – 0.34 = -1.91

…so both sums are less than -1.

Equally, an appreciation of the exchange rate will result in a deterioration of the trade balance, as exports fall faster than imports. At least, that’s what these figures suggest.

However, because I haven’t modeled feedback effects (except through the inclusion of the export series in the import demand equation), you should probably take these results with a bucket of salt. The fact that exports cause a one-to-one change in imports suggests that adding dynamics might change the picture dramatically, but I haven’t yet come up with a model I’m happy with.

I’m also working on breaking down the components of both exports and imports, which might yield further insights. One preliminary result that seems to be holding up: the exchange rate has no impact on imports of consumption or intermediate goods, which also suggests that the import demand functions I’ve estimated are questionable.

Technical Notes
1. Trade data from DOS
2. GDP data from IMF International Financial Statistics

Direct Investment, the Balance of Payments, and the International Investment Position

It’s no secret that capital has been leaving the country, even as the trade balance generates a continuous surplus. Breaking down the financial account of the balance of payments (BOP), here’s what Malaysia has experienced over the past ten years or so (1999-2008, RM Millions):



While FDI has been increasing, it doesn’t even begin to cover outward investment or the (negative) “other” investment. Portfolio investment has ebbed and flowed depending on the vagaries of the stock market, except for last year with a flight to safety from all emerging markets prompting a sell down of equities and other assets in favour of (paradoxically) USD assets. That spike has partially reversed in 2009.

The cumulative numbers are staggering: negative RM156.6 billion in outward direct investment, RM257.0 billion in other investment, and RM52.8 billion in portfolio investment, for a total outflow as at end of 2008 of RM 466.5 billion.

That’s right, nearly half a trillion Ringgit, or half of current M3.

The question is: is this outward flow occurring because foreigners are abandoning Malaysia as an investment destination, or is this Malaysian companies investing abroad? The former is downright bad for obvious reasons, while the latter is only somewhat good as it can be counterbalanced by subsequent inward income flows. Anecdotal evidence favours the latter, as there’s plenty of news of domestic corporations making big bets on other emerging markets – such as Maybank in Indonesia, and Maxis in India.

However, there is an inherent flaw in using BOP data to figure out where investment is actually going, because it is a flow measurement, not a stock measurement. With BOP data, we’re completely ignoring the possibility of reinvestment of profits and earnings. This doesn’t turn up in financial flows, and it’s difficult to judge private sector investment attitudes towards Malaysia based on BOP data alone.

It is more than possible that the outward flow of investment is due not only to Malaysian firms investing overseas, but also to foreign-owned firms redirecting investment overseas from retained profits generated locally. That in itself is not great news, but it’s certainly more palatable than foreign firms pulling up stakes and leaving. What we need is to get a view of foreign and domestic holdings of investment stock, not just flows as in the BOP, to get a better idea of what’s going on.

Luckily, we do actually have such a report – the International Investment Position. This is a relatively new set of statistical information (as such things go), and data availability is still very patchy for many countries. Malaysia’s for instance, only goes back to 2001 and was first published in 2005. Prior to the IIP, figuring out a country’s investment stock position (more commonly known as the net foreign asset position) was a matter of guesstimation and to be honest it still is, even with the IIP – you’re depending on accurate reporting to compile the statistics and there are many offshore money centers, some with dubious legal enforcement.

Be that as it may, the IIP makes for interesting reading. I’ve posted on Malaysia’s net foreign asset position, and the IIP (with some discrepancies) confirms the notion that Malaysia is now a net creditor nation (RM Millions):



Since we’re at the moment interested in the direct investment position, here’s both the asset and liabilities side (RM millions):

External Direct Investment Assets


External Direct Investment Liabilities


So we are primarily looking at Malaysians investing abroad, with a very small pullback in foreign inward investment in 2008, which is understandable given economic conditions over the past two years. The numbers don’t quite reconcile with the BOP data, mainly due to slightly different categorization as well as the element of reinvested earnings involved.

And of course, the net portfolio position is still sharply negative (RM millions):



But on the whole, we’re in a better than decent position here (assuming the positive IIP holds). Even though investment and capital are leaving the country, this is counterbalanced by an increase in future potential earnings from abroad, as well as less pressure to keep reserves high. This also puts upward pressure on the exchange rate.

Technical Notes
1. BOP data from BNM's Monthly Statistical Bulletin
2. The International Investment Position Reports available from DOS

Wednesday, October 21, 2009

Strong Vs Weak Ringgit Again

Izwan Idris asks if we should have a stronger Ringgit:

"One theory why the ringgit is limping behind its regional peers is that the ringgit basket is US dollar-heavy.

This explains why the currency continues to track the US dollar movement closely under the current 'managed float' system, rather than reflecting Malaysia’s own economic health.

Typically, a weak ringgit, in a way, works as a subsidy for local exporters by way of keeping export prices “competitive” against manufacturers based in other countries. This strategy helps local manufacturers earn more ringgit for every dollar sold but, on the flip side, Malaysians will have to pay more in ringgit for imported goods and services."


There are so many problems with this post I don't even know where to begin (and I'm not even going to comment on the grammar and tense usage mistakes).

So from the top (my comments in blue for legibility):

1. "The ringgit was officially de-pegged against the US dollar from a fixed rate of 3.80 on July 21, 2005 and, like the Singapore dollar, is currently under a float system tied to a basket of currencies."

Plain wrong. MAS follow an explicit exchange rate policy with interest rates and money supply free to vary (within limits), so that part is correct. BNM focuses on short term interest rates (the Official Policy Rate or OPR), with the exchange rate and money supply free to vary within limits in terms of volatility - so that part is false.

Fail.


2. "Economists estimate that the United States accounts for about 20% of Malaysia’s total trade, but as much of 80% of the country’s foreign transactions are denominated in US dollar."

I'll concede the latter statement (in the absence of firm evidence), but the former needs to be substantiated. Malaysia's direct trade with the US was last at 20% of total trade 10 years ago (the peak was 20.9% in 1998). As of last year, the US trade share has fallen to 11.8% - behind Singapore and approximately on par with Japan and China.

Big fail.


3. "One theory why the ringgit is limping behind its regional peers is that the ringgit basket is US dollar-heavy.

This explains why the currency continues to track the US dollar movement closely under the current “managed float” system, rather than reflecting Malaysia’s own economic health."

This is not a theory - it's a hypothesis, and an easily disproved one at that. First, as I pointed out in point 1. above, officially the Ringgit is in a free-float system, with the policy focus on interest rates rather than the exchange rate.

Second, if the Ringgit is truly tracking the USD then from a statistical perspective the MYRUSD rate should have a smaller standard deviation compared to other MYR cross rates. Out of the currencies of our major trading partners (sample 2005:6 to 2009:9, daily frequencies), the USD only ranks a distant third behind EUR and SGD, and only very marginally in front of CAD, GBP and SWF. Hardly conclusive evidence that we have a de facto peg to a USD-heavy basket.

Looking at the period when BNM was actively managing the exchange rate back in the 1980s bears this result out. For the sample 1980:1 to 1989:12 (again, daily frequencies), the USDMYR standard deviation was far and away the lowest by a couple of orders of magnitude, followed distantly by CAD and GBP, and even more distantly by the SGD, AUD, and ECU.

[Edit]: I should also point out that current MYRUSD volatility (as measured by the standard deviation) is 5x greater than it was in the 1980s.

Given relative movements and volatility in currencies against MYR over the past four years, if BNM is using a currency basket to "manage" the Ringgit, it's a very, very strange one.

Again, fail.


4. "The US dollar had fallen 15% against a basket of six major currencies since March, based on the performance of the US dollar index traded in New York. During this period, the won shot up 34% against the US dollar, followed by the rupiah’s 27% appreciation over the same period. The rupee gained 12%, while the Singapore dollar strengthened by 11%.

The ringgit lagged behind with a 10% rise, which was slightly better than the baht’s 9% advance."

This appears to imply (rather disingenuously) that MYR is being deliberately kept weak as regional currencies have advanced more than the MYR. In academic economic circles, this is an example of "data-mining" - selecting the data or the model that best supports your hypothesis or preconceptions, and hang the bigger picture.

To show what I mean, here are the percentage movements in the 2008:9 to 2009:2 timeframe (i.e. from the beginning of the financial meltdown to approximately the lowest point):

a. USD Major Currencies Index = +13.1%
b. KRW = -40.8%
c. IDR = -30.8%
d. INR = -17.6%
e. SGD = -9.1%
f. MYR = -9.2%
g. THB = -5.6%

We have an almost mirror image from the statistics quoted in the article. MYR hasn't gained much in the last six months or so, for the simple reason that it didn't fall as much during the worse of the crisis.

As Benjamin Disraeli was once purported to have said, "There are three kinds of lies: lies, damned lies, and statistics."

Fail.


5. "At near-0% interest, the US dollar is a cheap currency to borrow, but yields almost nothing to keep. Savvy international investors lend money in the United States and use the cash to buy assets elsewhere."

Let's be charitable - I can only think of this (emphasis mine) as a typo. It should be borrow not lend.

6. "Commodities and Asian equities are the big winners. Gold, which is the traditional hedge, is now trading at record high of US$1,065 an ounce.

Indonesian stocks have the highest return in US dollar terms year-to-date. The Jakarta Composite Index rose 84% in its local currency, but shot up 122% if the gains are reflected in US dollar.

At 1,265 points yesterday, the FBM KL Composite’s 48% rise year-to-date was the least among other regional stock indices."


Same as point 4 above - we haven't risen as much, because we didn't lose so much during the depths of the crisis either. Using the same sample period as my currency example (Oct 2008-Feb 2009), the JKSE fell 40.6% during that period and was 54.6% off its all time high. The KLCI by comparison fell just 19.1%, and was 41.3% off its all time high. A more regional comparison also holds - the KLCI was among the better performers in terms of holding its value in the past two years.

Do I sense a pattern here? Fail.


7. "High income equals to high purchasing power. To achieve this, it will require shifting the whole economy away from its current low-cost manufacturing base to a more service-oriented one, which is more or less what Singaporeans had done."

Finally a sensible statement - which unfortunately completely missed the connection between a stronger exchange value and having a services-based, high income economy. The latter begets the former, not the other way around. Singapore has an appreciating currency vis-à-vis Malaysia, because they have a stronger services (non-tradables) sector. There's also the demographic angle: countries with higher youth dependency ratios tend to have "weaker" currencies, and Singapore is "aging" faster than Malaysia is.

Going for a strong currency policy without improvement in the non-tradables sector is a triumph of form over substance.


8. "Keeping the ringgit undervalue against its regional counterpart may be counter-productive in the longer run, as it will only fuel our addiction to cheap exports industries that only attract unskilled foreign labour."

What's truly ironic is that having a "cheap" currency is not necessarily an advantage when you have low-value added export industries (i.e. with high import content), and especially not when a portion of your exports is commodity based. I'll touch on this when I get around to posting on trade elasticities. He made the point earlier when talking about the effect of exchange rates on exports and imports (see quote at the top of this post), but again missed the connection.

But as I've extensively written on before (for instance here, here, and here), I do not believe the Ringgit is substantially undervalued based on Malaysia's economic structure and current fundamentals (like terms of trade, services/exports shares, trade barriers, capital and financial stocks and flows etc). Nor do I believe that there is an implicit policy to keep the MYR undervalued relative to any currency. As far as I'm concerned, MYR is close to its trade-weighted fair value with a bias towards appreciation as the country increasingly shifts towards services as the growth sector.


Technical Notes:
1. MYRUSD exchange rates and MYR cross rates against other currencies derived from the Federal Reserve's Report H.10, except for IDR, where data was sourced from Pacific Exchange Rate Service.

2. Stock market index data from Yahoo! Finance.

Tuesday, October 20, 2009

Tan Sri Governor's Thoughts On MYR...

...are the same as mine:

"Asked if the ringgit should not be allowed to appreciate too much as economic growth could be affected, she said the current level of the currency actually reflected the country's economic fundamentals.

'I want to emphasise that our export sector has been resilient despite the appreciation of the ringgit,' she said."


Read the rest of her comments here. Regardless of this consistently given message (I've heard this same comment from her quite a few times in the past four years), I don't think any diehards are going to change their position that the Ringgit is undervalued.

I'm still working on the promised post on trade elasticities - or rather, trying to find the time to work on it - but my first impressions were correct.

Yup, my initial work-ups were wrong.

I was looking primarily at the time series properties of exports and imports as they relate to the exchange rate. After a quick run through of the literature, turns out that you should actually do fully-specified export and import demand models. Since that's beyond the scope of this blog, I'm working on reduced-form models (only essential variables, not too many lags). At the moment I'm getting some unexpected results, even by my stubbornly contrarian standards.

What's this to do with exchange rates? It has to do with the second part of her comment, on trade. Stay tuned.

Monday, October 19, 2009

Random Thoughts on Budget 2010

I'll be honest - I've never been good at reading the tea leaves when it comes to the budget, except in aggregate. Micro-level policy has never been my strong suit, and I'm far more comfortable diagnosing monetary policy and real indicators. Having said that, given the crossroads that Malaysia is at, it's such an interesting period to be an economics observer (or voyeur if you prefer), that I really can't pass this up. Be warned, this is going to somewhat of a stream-of-conciousness post, with no real point to make!

My macro-view of the economy has evolved, but not changed significantly in the last six months. I think the stimulus packages were on balance necessary and useful, if only to turn around consumer and business confidence rather than any real effects they may have on the economy. I suppose it'd be nice to have the morale boost without the financial outlay, but I'm not sure people (including politicians themselves) would accept that, especially in the heat of the crisis. The national debt is climbing rapidly, but not to any serious level as yet, and certainly well below any point where borrowing costs or domestic liquidity becomes a problem.

Real indicators are generally all creeping up, Aug/Sept slowdowns notwithstanding. As I've talked about before, this is a factor of Ramadhan/Eid el Fitri artificially crimping output. I've already recorded that the economy has already passed the recession stage and (because of the eccentricities of Malaysian statistical computations) we should see official confirmation next month when the 3Q figures are scheduled to be released. I'm still concerned that this recovery may turn out to be inventory-driven which may see us slowing again in the next couple of quarters, but I'd say a "W"-shaped recovery isn't a high probability at this stage.

So it's time to deal with the structural headwinds besetting the Malaysian economy, where fiscal policy is best effective (or least damaging, depending on your philosophical viewpoint). What are the key problems? In no particular order...

1. Caught in a middle income trap
2. Youth unemployment
3. Poor R&D spending
4. Quality education
5. Affordable healthcare and housing
6. Ineffective transport (and auto) policy
7. Subsidy mentality
8. Income inequality
9. Low-value added manufacturing
10. Declining oil reserves (and thus future oil revenues)
11. Narrow tax base

...and the list goes on. I'm sure I've left quite a few biggies off.

There's no way the government (or any government) will make headway in all these areas in one year, or even during the 5-year period of our development plans.

One key thing I am happy with is the shift to a services-based growth strategy. I've been talking about this as the way to go since around 2005, when it became obvious that export-led manufacturing had reached a dead-end - despite a global trade boom, Malaysian electronics exports flat-lined from that point on. A services-based strategy would be the logical evolution of the economy, one which other high income countries have already undergone. Because the labour market would be less affected by international arbitrage, incomes should rise independently of productivity as labour demand in the services sector rises. This shift should also help to resolve some of the problems in the list above, and incidentally put upward pressure on the exchange rate.

I remember reading Morgan Stanley's Global Economic Forum (good for a quick, intelligent view of economic happenings around the world - Stephen Roach was the Guru for me) back in 2005-2006, that Malaysia should explicitly follow a dual-track, hybrid strategy - both export-led manufacturing as well as export commodities-based. Thailand was put up as a good example to follow. I think that's a step sideways more than anything - you're depending on a lack of correlation between the two sectors to maintain domestic economic activity.

Still, that was a few years lost in getting a leg up the income ladder. One of the problems (of many) with a centrally directed strategy is that bureaucrats will tend to stick with a particular solution, even when it's obviously not working (like investment quotas). In this case, I'm wondering if we've left it too late. The increasing adoption of the internet as a business tool means that costs of communications has dropped rapidly, which reduces some of the barriers that hitherto have isolated domestic services sectors from foreign competition.

Oh, there certainly continues to be high barriers to labour mobility, especially in high-income professional services (lawyers) and in low-income services (think fast food), but for some things like shopping, the market is truly international. That complicates and makes more difficult gains from a services-based growth strategy, which depends in large part on restricted market access and labour market immobility.

Having said that, the alternatives are unpalatable - commodities are inherently volatile, even if it has supplemented export incomes in the last four years. High value-added domestic manufacturing isn't likely to take hold, unless we do something really drastic with our truly pathetic private and public R&D spending and poor corporate-academic cooperation.

So what do I expect from the 2010 Budget? Forget any bones for the consumer - adult unemployment has barely ticked up, real wages have continued to rise (except in manufacturing), and consumer spending is up. I don't think we will see any progress in implementing GST either, especially with the political bugbear of potentially higher prices. Civil service wages should continue to go up, although Cuepacs is whistling in the wind if they think they can get two months bonus. The boost in wages is necessary, to push up incomes especially for some of the lower paid civil servants as well as reduce the temptation towards venal corruption.

While I think the government will try to keep operational expenditure below expected revenue, that's a tough job in the present state of the economy. I don't think revenues will drop as much as people expect, but the operational budget should still be in the red. Which means after tacking on the development budget, we're still looking at a substantial fiscal deficit, I'm thinking in the range of 4%-5% of GDP. Whatever the planned figure however, I do expect actual 2010 expenditure to come in at a more palatable ratio, if revenues come in higher as I expect.

Friday, October 16, 2009

Why The IMF Thinks MYR Is Undervalued

In keeping with the forex theme this week, in my last post I pointed out that Singapore is accumulating international reserves at a faster pace than Malaysia, but yet is considered to have a "strong" currency. Later I linked to research that suggested that SGD was as undervalued as the MYR, while the IMF suggested SGD was only slightly undervalued. Why the divergence in opinion?

There is of course the difference in methodologies used to determine currency misalignments (which I talked about here, here and here). But what I'd like to point out today are two potential issues that may be affecting MYR currency misalignment analysis.

The first issue lies with differences in calculating the real effective exchange rate index (REER) itself which may be to blame. To illustrate, here are my calculated nominal and real indexes, compared with the published IMF calculated indexes:





Notice that the nominal indexes are more or less equivalent, with any differences attributable to the currencies included in the basket as well as changes in the weighting scheme. I calculate my indexes with weights changing on a quarterly basis, while the IMF changes once every five-ten years or so - but doesn't appear to make a significant difference here.

There is however a substantial divergence in the REER indexes, with the IMF REER much higher in 2008 - and thus indicating that the nominal rate is too low, and the exchange rate is undervalued. The main difference between the real and nominal indexes is the application of price deflators in the real index, which are used to adjust currency values based on inflation. For the IMF index, CPI inflation is generally used for most countries except for OECD members, where unit labour costs are substituted.

Since CPI inflation can more readily go negative than unit labour costs (as we've seen this past year), that puts an upward bias into the IMF's REER index in periods of disinflation or deflation, especially with OECD countries taking more than a third of the total weight in the MYR index.

Another issue is one of export structure. Most analysis, including the one I linked to in the last post, use aggregate exports when running regressions (heck, so do I). The problem here is that when there is a commodity bubble, prices might go up without output necessarily increasing to the same degree. For example, palm oil and rubber (log annual changes, export volumes and values):




If the increase represents a transitory change, then the degree of currency adjustment required to rebalance the current account will be inflated - hence current account approaches to exchange rate determination, such as used in the aforementioned paper and in two of the three methodologies used by the IMF, would tend to overstate the equilibrium level of the exchange rate.

As an aside, I made the point in my last post that positive terms of trade shocks would see the income effect dominate, and would not reduce volumes very much. The behaviour of agricultural commodity exports over the past few years is certainly suggestive that my conjecture is worth considering.

Thursday, October 15, 2009

Stronger Exchange Rate ≠ Strong Exchange Rate Policy

Jagdev Singh Sidhu over at The Star thinks we should pursue a strong currency policy because:

"A stronger ringgit will force Malaysians, both employees and employers, to be more efficient and that is something the economy needs to do as I feel it is somewhat in an economic mid-life crisis."

He also makes the statement that:

"The current preference of using interest rates to drive economic growth may be due for a re-think in favour of the currency as the lower-than-normal rates in Malaysia since the Asian financial crisis haven’t really worked."

And third:

"A stronger ringgit is no guarantee that the country will be able to make that transition to a high-income economy but there are a couple of examples nearby which we should look at.

Singapore and Taiwan endured short-term pains when they allowed their currencies to appreciate but they did make the adjustment to incorporate more skills and capital in manufacturing processes. The stronger currency was also a boost for the service sector in those countries."


As you can imagine, I’m going to pick a few holes in this argument.

The first statement assumes that the substitution effect dominates the income effect in the terms of trade (the purchasing power of money we receive from exports, relative to what we can buy of imports). In other words, a stronger exhange rate reduces our competitiveness and we have to become more efficient to continue to sell to external markets.

The general consensus and the empirical evidence in the research literature finds just the opposite. In other words, higher terms of trade (which is what you get with a stronger exchange rate) actually increases export revenues more than the loss coming from reduced demand. So there won’t be much impact in terms of forcing Malaysians to “be more efficient”. In fact, given the relative share of primary resources in exports, there’s probably going to be even less incentive to improve productivity.

A second point is that because of our low value-added industries and with multi-nationals involved in exports, strengthening the exchange rate should in fact have only marginal effects on incomes and trade volume because there’s little local currency pass-through. A higher exchange rate not only reduces the local currency value of exports, but at the same time reduces the local currency value of imported inputs. Assuming the exchange rate elasticities are equivalent, then there will be roughly no change in returns to local content.

Third, given the two effects above, it’s not obvious or automatic that a stronger exchange rate would raise labour incomes in the export sector. Because the income effect dominates, trade volumes will change very little in the manufactured sector, so demand for labour will not change much or at all – which means whatever excess returns are generated from a higher exchange rate will benefit owners of capital, not labour. This also true to a lesser degree for the primary resources sector, where the ratio of imported inputs (e.g. in CPO) is actually quite high. This is not a recipe for raising domestic income levels.

The second statement is really about the conduct of monetary policy in pursuing price stability and economic growth, with the priority on the former as it is also a precondition for the latter. The choices a central bank can make here are setting the monetary base (money supply targeting), setting the price of money (interest rate targeting), and setting the relative price of money (exchange rate targeting). More recently, some central banks have experimented with direct inflation targeting with some success, but our statistical capabilities have to be upgraded for that to happen here.

The first option is a proven failure after experimentation in the early 1980s in the US and UK, and gave rise to Goodhart’s Law. The second has had relative success in maintaining price stability over the past twenty years.

The third is only advisable for relatively small economies with high external exposure or for countries with no external credibility, because in essence it means abdication of any influence over domestic monetary conditions. That’s fairly obvious from the experience of both Singapore and Hong Kong, the two countries in East Asia that use exchange-rate targeting – interest rates and monetary aggregates are subject to far more volatility than countries that use interest rate targeting. It’s also interesting to note that Malaysia’s aggregate economic record in the last decade is marginally better than Singapore’s and much better than Hong Kong’s.

Given this weakness, I don’t see any advantages for Malaysia, with its much more diversified economy, to follow this route. Since the first option is also out, that leaves only interest rate, and potentially, inflation targeting as the basis for monetary policy.

Also, from a currency perspective, it’s not the nominal interest rate that matters but the real interest rate differential. While both nominal and real interest rates have been low across the last decade, that’s consistent with the rest of the world (trade-weighted, real interest rate differential):



In fact, it looks remarkably stable to me since 1990. The implication of course is that with interest rate targeting, both the exchange rate and money supply growth would be inherently more volatile, which has indeed been the case:

Growth in Monetary Aggregates (log annual changes)


Nominal and Real Effective Exchange Rate Indexes (2000=100)


On that basis, since 2005 it’s hard to say that BNM has any currency policy at all, apart from occasional intervention to smoothen volatility as happened this past week.

Now, one might argue that the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves in the past 10 years is a sure sign that the currency is weak, and that the central bank is intervening to prevent currency appreciation. That’s only true if you think the standard open-economy model applies. But that makes it hard to reconcile Singapore’s reserve accumulation with their alleged strong currency policy:

Singapore's International Reserves


My critique is that many who take reserve accumulation as proof of a weak currency policy are ignoring the money supply implication of a trade surplus and capital flows, and the potential for financial fragility inherent with a large accumulation of foreign exchange deposits in the banking system (FX deposits are included in both M2 and M3).

On a more practical basis, it also makes sense for banks to sell their excess forex deposits to BNM since you can’t spend or lend those deposits within Malaysia. Hence inflows of foreign exchange raises demand for local currency, which causes interest rates to rise. Since we have an interest rate targeting regime, that requires the central bank to increase liquidity which damps pressure on interest rates, and incidentally involves selling Ringgit in return for foreign exchange.

Rather than a sign of currency intervention, accumulation of reserves then becomes a form of insurance, in short making sure enough foreign exchange is on hand in case of liquidity emergencies, such as occurred late last year when investor flight to quality caused a USD shortage the world over:

Net Official Reserves


Change in Net Official Reserves


The problem is that open market liquidity operations to manage money supply volatility, conducted in foreign exchange, is functional equivalent to foreign exchange rate intervention and vice-versa. You can’t tell the difference, and it is hardly proof that the central bank is taking any particular stance with respect to the currency, as opposed to domestic liquidity.

On the third statement, you can only accept that Singapore and Taiwan have “strong currency policies” if you believe that Purchasing Power Parity applies (PPP). Otherwise, the latest IMF Article IV consultation with Singapore indicates the SGD to be undervalued and other research (this for instance) indicates that both SGD and NTD are as undervalued as the MYR. The equivalent, opposite statement can actually be made about the USD - its highly overvalued and ought to depreciate relative to everybody else. The truth is probably somewhere in the middle.

And if you followed my writings at all, you’ll know that I believe that the causality between the services sector and the exchange rate runs the opposite from what is stated in the article – a stronger services sector creates an appreciation of the currency, not the other way around.

Bottom line? I don’t believe we have a currency policy at all – the preponderance of evidence suggests that BNM is only concerned with currency volatility, not its level or stability. On that basis, the MYR will continue to trade at or close to its short term, time-varying equilibrium (barring intervention) and gently move towards its medium term, fundamentally consistent equilibrium over the medium term (4-5 years) – which at the present time means an appreciation.

That doesn’t mean there won’t be large currency moves, against the USD for instance which has a lot of structural problems. But interference in the exchange rate won’t solve our structural problems – in fact a strong currency policy is more likely to paper over the problems we have than become a force for change. The MYR will get stronger, but as a consequence of a services-based economic growth strategy. As the fundamentals change, so will the equilibrium exchange rate level.

Q3 2009 MYR Exchange Rates Review

I realized a couple of days ago that I hadn’t done an update on the Ringgit for quite some time. As I got started I remembered why – out of all the data I’m tracking, forex is by far the hardest and most complex to manage.

First because (unlike most) my approach goes beyond the USD exchange rate, and second is because I calculate the trade-weighted indexes, the data problems can occasion some hair-pulling. The actual forex and trade data are easy to get even across the fifteen currencies I use in the broad nominal index, but getting timely up-to-date information on price deflators for calculating the inflation adjusted index isn’t.

For instance, Australia (of all people) only publishes quarterly series for their CPI, which requires interpolation to the monthly frequencies I’m using. China on the other hand does publish monthly but only for year-on-year index movements, which means actual monthly inflation is really a matter of guesswork.

Both these countries matter because without more granular info on Australian CPI I can only calculate the real effective (inflation adjusted, trade-weighted) index once a quarter and with a lag of up to two months, and because movement in the Yuan accounts for nearly 15% of the real index. Having inaccuracies in either of these currency cross rates would increase the error rate of the calculated indexes, and incidentally my own peace of mind.

Having said that, there’s been quite a bit of change on the forex front especially over the past month, so a review would be useful. I also took the time to work a bit more on exchange rate elasticities as it relates to trade, and the results are fascinating to say the least – assuming of course, I’m doing this at all correctly. But trade elasticities will have to wait, as this post will be long enough already.

First, the overall view (2000=100):



The MYR has lost quite a bit of ground since the end of 2007, but there are signs things are turning around. My view (which by all accounts isn’t very popular) is that MYR was overvalued at the end of 2007, and the retracement was justified, if a bit overdone. That’s fairly common in currency markets – the overshooting I mean. Right now we’re probably a little (2%-3%) under the short term equilibrium, and just a bit more (4%-5%) under the medium term equilibrium level.

I have to digress here to explain the equilibrium terminology:

1. Short term equilibrium is the market-clearing equilibrium, where demand and supply of currency match. It’s also the equilibrium consistent with relative real interest rates.

2. Medium term equilibrium refers to the equilibrium justified by flow fundamentals – like changes in terms of trade, government spending, GDP and the current account.

3. Long term equilibrium is a stock equilibrium, which is the point the exchange rate is consistent with holdings of both (financial and real) assets and liabilities.

It’s hard to put a time period to any of these definitions, as they differ according to the structure of a country’s economy, its external exposure, and the dynamics of its exchange rate, but generally short-term means 1 year or less, medium term is anywhere up to 4-5 years, and long term any period over that. Of course, any change in economic fundamentals means that any given equilibrium is a moving target – again not a very popular view outside of academia.

But to get back to what’s happening with MYR, here’s MYR movements against the major currencies (2000=100):






Note that the MYR is close to its short-term fair value against both USD and especially EUR, but grossly undervalued against the JPY. I’m interpreting it in this fashion based on the differential between the nominal and real indexes here – the general rule of thumb is that the nominal rate should move towards the real rate. I’m also using the year 2000 as an equilibrium reference point, which believe it or not is the consensus among the studies I’ve seen, including the IMF’s.

The reason for the JPY gap can squarely by blamed on the JPY carry trade, which involves borrowing in JPY and investing in higher yielding currencies (e.g. AUD and NZD). In currency trading terms, that means short JPY and long AUD for instance. One interesting thing going on now is that the carry trade business is increasingly moving to USD (hence the general JPY strengthening trend), so we’re likely to see MYR overshoot above its equilibrium level against the USD – that ought to make all the “weak currency policy” conspiracy theorists happy.

The two other major currencies of importance to MYR are CNY and SGD (2000=100):




These five currencies each have a weight exceeding 10% in my indexes, and collectively form about two-thirds of the movements. The CNY rate is fairly close if a little undervalued, but for SGD, MYR does look more than a little overvalued. That appears to be consistent with recent IMF assessment of the SGD, in that the SGD is undervalued relative to its medium term level.

As for the rest of the currencies in the basket, I won’t post detailed charts unless someone asks for them, except to note that there has been a general trend of appreciation in the MYR particularly against the GBP and Indian Rupee (INR), except for against the AUD which went through a roller-coaster ride over the last year (2000=100):



Again, this has been a function of the carry trade, in which the AUD was one of the main targets. The onset of the financial crisis in August last year caused a sharp pullback in risk taking among international investors, including unwinding of currency positions. That helped boost the JPY, and prompted a selldown of target currencies like the AUD. As normalcy returned, so did the carry trade – hence the recovery in AUD.

I should note here that the INR, IDR (Indonesian Rupiah), PHP (Philippines Peso) and VND (Vietnam Dong) all look overvalued relative to the MYR to me, but that’s consistent with their relatively smaller trade exposure and regulated capital accounts. Unless the latter is opened up, these currencies should keep their elevated status. On the other hand, MYR appears overvalued against both HKD and TWD.

Technical Notes:
1. Forex data from the Pacific Exchange Rate Service.
2. CPI data from DOS, International Labour Organization, Eurostat, Australian Bureau of Statistics, and the General Statistics Office of Vietnam.

Tuesday, October 13, 2009

August Industrial Production: Don't Mind The Dip

As before, and for the duration, I'm going to focus on levels rather than growth data. For anyone who's interested, here's the month-on-month growth for Industrial Production Index and its components (log monthly changes, seasonally adjusted):



Annual growth data of course isn't terribly informative with all the growth figures continuing to be in the red, save for the electricity index. If you've followed my last few posts, you'll know that even standard seasonal adjustment methodologies aren't a panacea, since fasting month follows a lunar not solar, calender. As such, August's slight downturn in seasonally adjusted month-on-month growth for all the components save manufacturing, shouldn't be taken too seriously and shouldn't be taken to be the start of something more pernicious.

Looking at the index levels shows a picture of gradual and moderate recovery in industrial output, save for mining, with July and August flattening out (2000=100):



This could in fact be taken to be a good sign, if my hypothesis that fasting month impeded output growth in August and September turn out to be true - more so since the manufacturing index has continued to push higher. On that basis I'd expect much stronger overall growth beginning this month, which we should see confirmed by mid-December.

The level of the electricity index - it's not far off it's all-time high - prompted me to think about capacity utilisation. We don't have official published surveys on this, so speculation is as far as it goes, but fitting trendlines (beginning 2000:01) to the indexes seemed like a reasonable rule of thumb approach to figuring out the gap between production and available capacity, so here goes:

Industrial Production Index


Mining Index


Manufacturing Index


Electricity Index


Adding together the gap between previous highs and the trendline, and the gap between current output and the trendline, as the current output gap, I got these numbers:

Overall IPI: 82.4%
Mining: 89.0%
Electricity: 90.6%
Manufacturing: 78.6%

The manufacturing number appears to too high to me based on media reports, but that's an artifact of assuming that peak production coincided with full capacity utilisation. So these numbers (obviously very rough) would actually represent an upper bound to current capacity utilisation. Still this may be useful barometer to follow in the future.

Technical Notes:
1. August Industrial Production Report is available from the Department of Statistics.

Saturday, October 10, 2009

August Trade

Sometimes, it's depressing when you get proven right. In a previous post, I talked about the probability of August data showing a downturn due to the beginning of fasting month. Lo and behold, both exports and imports fell in August (log annual and monthly changes):




Worse, both fell on a seasonally adjusted basis as well (log monthly changes):



About the only bright spot was a jump in crude oil exports, but you can put that down almost entirely to rising international crude oil prices, not an increase in export volume.

Whether the August figures are really bad depends on how you interpret the seasonal effects. On the one hand, the drop could be signaling that the inventory correction (see last month's trade post) that exporters are undergoing could be ending, which means worse trade numbers going forward. On the other hand, the fact that fasting month is not a fixed solar calender event means that my seasonally adjusted figures aren't fully taking into account the impact it has on output, and may be overestimating where the data should be. I'd prefer to believe the latter is happening, but we'll see how it goes the next couple of months.

Forecast updates:
Seasonally Adjusted Model


Point forecast:RM43461, Range forecast:RM48847-RM38074

Seasonal Effect Model


Point forecast:RM47541, Range forecast:RM54175-RM40906


Technical Notes:
1. Trade Data from Matrade

Friday, October 9, 2009

DAP Alternative Budget

I did a quick flip through of DAP's effort at presenting their version of what Malaysia's spending priorities should be in the next fiscal year - obviously not doing much justice to the evident amount of work put in. Once you get past the political polemics, there is a lot to like. In no particular order of importance (or relevance!), my comments on what struck me the most:

1. I like many of the proposals regarding education, especially keeping PPSMI, as well as decoupling university payscales from civil service pay grades.

2. Ditto healthcare.

3. While there is no doubt public transport is in a mess, I'm not sure adding another layer of bureaucracy by creating transport authorities at municipal, state and federal level is a great idea.

4. On the other hand, will all political parties work together to bring back local council elections? Please!? This won't just have the effect of promoting accountability and reduce opportunity for corruption at the local level, it should also serve as a good training ground for young politicians.

5. Getting back to transport, I have reservations about the proposal to nationalise toll roads. I won't argue with the financial aspects, but I am concerned about efficiency - the toll concessionaires have an incentive to provide a quality product and service. I seriously don't think JKR will do as well, either in maintenance nor in keeping future costs down.

6. Tying state grants to a formula is a good idea - but basing it mainly on a per capita formula is not. We want to promote regional development (particularly in the East coast and Sabah and Sarawak), and while there is a transfer mechanism, I don't think it goes far enough.

7. The proposed revisions of the poverty line income calculations are great, and comments about income inequality (as measured by the Gini coefficient) are very apt. But I would rather see more detailed studies in this area, mainly because to me, inequality is and would be less of an issue if the lower income groups have sufficient income for a decent quality of life, and also if income growth keeps pace with the economy (implying that inequality in incomes is not reflecting inequality in economic opportunities). If both these conditions are met, then I don't see relative inequality as an economic as opposed to a political problem.

Unfortunately, the way the Gini coefficient is calculated tends to overlook this, as it really basically only compares the highest income brackets against the lowest. You don't get a sense of how the middle-classes really stand in relation, and from a political point of view (and I'm departing from my economics focus here), that's where the crucial votes and vote leaders really lie.

8. One critique I have is the characterisation of the BN government as being grossly fiscally irresponsible. I don't necessarily see that at all. While it's true that oil revenues have underwritten an increasing portion of government expenditure, looking back at the historical data provides some perspective. First the fiscal balance as a ratio to nominal GDP (annual data up to 2008):



Note that apart from a short period in the mid-1990s, the government has always run a deficit. The deficits run this past decade are just par for the course. Second, while the absolute value of the national debt has increased, its ratio to nominal GDP began falling when Pak Lah took over:



There will of course be a substantial increase this year and next (both relative and absolute) due to the stimulus packages, but very few will argue against the political if not economic necessity of that. What isn't shown in the data is that over the past few years, the Treasury has basically gotten rid of almost all our foreign borrowings. Here's Malaysia's net foreign asset position (public+private) up to 2007 (ratio to nominal GDP):



That means the government only has to worry about domestic uptake of government securities issuance - and no that doesn't necessarily mean there is a risk of crowding out (FI reserve balances with BNM):



There's so much excess liquidity sloshing around that banks might actually be glad to put their money in something both highly rated and earning some interest. Even at the rate the government is borrowing this year, I don't see any risk of crowding out of private investment until at least 2011 at the earliest, and the likelihood of that is pretty small.

Tuesday, October 6, 2009

August 2009 Monetary Policy Update

Over the Raya holidays, I’ve taken a short break from blogging – family and getting back to work commitments has meant limited time or energy for looking at the economic situation. Plus it’s the start of football season (no, not this type of football, I mean this one - I’m actually watching the Monday Night Football stream right now) so there’s been plenty of distractions the past couple of weeks. But there’s some interesting developments going on and there’s the run up to the tabling of the Budget at the end of this month, which means I’ll hopefully be posting pretty frequently from now on.

But talking about Raya holidays provides a nice segue into what the numbers will say about the economy in August and September. I’ve been harping about seasonal adjustments a great deal in this blog, and holidays are a great example of how differing work/holiday conditions impact economic output. In other words, don’t be surprised if the numbers appear to have turned down the last couple of months – I don’t think I was the only one to take a break off from work or slowed down during fasting month. Looking at the August numbers appears to bear this out.

First, BNM always increases the currency in circulation just prior to Hari Raya and Chinese New Year – no prizes for guessing why. You’d therefore expect to see a jump in money supply figures around those times but especially in M1, as is the case this August (log annual and log monthly changes):




Based on what I’ve described, I wouldn’t ordinarily put too much weight on this increase in monetary aggregates as signaling further monetary easing by BNM or as an autonomous jump in financial activity. There is one interesting anomaly however, with foreign currency deposits in the banking system jumping by RM8.6 billion in August, which is about 2/3rds of the increase in M2:



There’s no obvious reason that I can find for the increase, as neither the stock market nor the Ringgit budged very much in August. International reserves are also up, so BNM has obviously taken some steps to drain forex deposits from the system (log monthly changes in international reserves):



…but that leaves the increase in the banking system unexplained. I’m not sure at this stage whether I want to speculate as to why.

Moving on, loan growth has decelerated (log monthly changes):



…but as I said, this is probably more a function of getting into fasting month and what it entails for output. To underscore what I mean, here’s the loan growth data for working capital and credit cards (log monthly changes):





Since there is an expected drop in output, loan demand from businesses will fall and there will be a corresponding increase in consumption. No surprises here. The corollary is that the opposite should occur after Hari Raya (or Chinese New Year), in other words a drop (or deceleration) in monetary aggregates, increase in business demand for loans, while consumption loans drop.

Now you may ask why I don’t just seasonally adjust the figures in this case, as I’ve done previously? If you haven’t the time or inclination to apply seasonal adjustments (as I explained here) but still want to eyeball the data yourself, it pays to keep potential seasonal factors in mind. Another issue is that seasonal adjustments as applied to Malaysian data are a bit problematical because neither Hari Raya nor Chinese New Year is based on the solar calendar. That means the “seasonal effect” doesn’t occur in the same period every year, which makes statistical treatment a little difficult. Knowing how the numbers react during particular periods therefore helps analysis.

Having said that, seasonally adjusting the numbers doesn’t change the viewpoint very much:

M1 (log monthly changes):


Loan Growth (log monthly changes):


On the interest rate front, lending rates have continued to drift lower – which as far as I’m concerned is good news. What I find interesting is that the lending margin has drifted below the 3% level previously identified as being required for banks to survive an increase in NPLs while maintaining profitability (see this post for details):



This is probably a function of NPLs not actually rising very much during this downturn, which means that banks could be more comfortable competing on price without jeopardizing their capital base at a time when loan demand is softening:



The only other interest rate story of interest (pardon the pun), is in MGS:



Note the flattening of the yield curve at the long end – yields for 10-20-year MGS have dropped between 20bp-30bp in the July-August timeframe, and another 5bp or so in September. Looking back, I think that uncertainty over the public borrowing requirement a few months back really drove prices down. What we’re seeing now is a calmer market, especially since there’s now little support (or requirement) for a third stimulus package and noises from the government about fiscal consolidation in operational expenditure.